(1869-1944)听
STEPHEN LEACOCK, Economist:
An Owl Among the Parrots
by Myron J. Frankman
In David Staines, ed. (1986) Stephen Leacock: A Reappraisal. Ottawa: University of Ottawa Press, 51-58.
Stephen Leacock the economist is a forgotten man. He is not cited by economists. He left no Leacock school, no Leacock theory, no Leacock effect, nor is there even, surprisingly, a catch phrase associated with his name, such as Thorstein Veblen鈥檚 鈥渃onspicuous consumption.鈥 What was for many years a virtually final judgement of 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 scholarly work was pronounced by Harold Innis in a 1938 lecture at the University of Toronto. That lecture, which was intended to pay tribute to Leacock as one of the founders of Canadian social studies, was eventually published as his obituary in 1944 in the Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science.1 With but one exception, Innis chose to refer to Leacock as a political scientist rather than as an economist or even a political economist, although 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 1903 Ph.D. degree from The University of Chicago was in political economy. Though Innis drew links between Leacock and other economists such as Thorstein Veblen, Adam Smith, and Jacob Viner, he glossed over 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 writings on economic questions in favour of attention to his humour, which he regarded as having suffered from the influences of social science. In the opinion of Innis, 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 humour was 鈥渄estined not to endure鈥 for 鈥渋t is written in water and reflects too accurately the atmosphere of its period to interest later readers.鈥2 As for 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 academic work, in Innis鈥 view it suffered either from the 鈥渋mperialistic blight鈥3 or from the insufficiency of his preparation in the social sciences.4 One suspects that Innis masked his own view only thinly when he attributed to 鈥渟ome malicious individual鈥 the question 鈥淲hat is left of Stephen Leacock?鈥5 which was said to have been a response to 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 鈥淲hat is left of Adam Smith?鈥6
In the four decades since 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 death the only important notice taken of his social science writings was by Alan Bowker, who in 1973 republished The Unsolved Riddle of Social Justice, with other essays, under the title of The Social Criticism of Stephen Leacock. Bowker鈥檚 introduction is a useful complement to Innis鈥 evaluation, but we still lack a careful look at 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 economic ideas. Bowker shares in part Innis鈥 judgement that 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 humour was strengthened at the expense of his writings in the social sciences.7 For Bowker the turning point is 1920; after that Leacock is said to have seen himself primarily as a humorist, whose economic proposals 鈥渨ere in large part repetitious of his pre-1920 programmes and. . .were increasingly half-baked and badly written.8 鈥淚n fact, most of 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 economic writings were done after 1920. Moreover, in May 1930 Leacock wrote from Orillia to 成人VR视频鈥檚 principal, Sir Arthur Currie, to advise him, 鈥淚 have only five more sessions at 成人VR视频 and I intend [to] raise hell in Canadian economics during the short time left to me.鈥9 Nor does a man who sees himself primarily as a humorist turn down US$1,000 plus expenses to entertain the American Bankers鈥 Association in New York and offer instead to come at his own expense to speak 鈥渙n the restoration of the gold standard or some equally important subject.鈥10
Intellectual Influences:
To understand better 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 economic writings and his other writings as well, it is useful to examine the principal intellectual influences on Leacock. For Innis the following explanation sufficed: 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 鈥渨ork has been solidly based on the individualistic approach which characterized a rural background and his interest in humour.鈥11 Such a representation obscures rather than clarifies. W. A. Mackintosh, in his 1938 lecture on Adam Shortt, refers to the possibility of including in Who鈥檚 Who an intellectual pedigree of scholars, and suggests 鈥淚nnis, H. A., by Thorstein Veblen out of Adam Shortt.鈥12 In a like manner I propose 鈥淟eacock, S. B., by Veblen out of John Stuart Mill.鈥
The origins of what Innis called the 鈥渋ndividualistic approach鈥 can be traced directly to Mill, whose Principles of Political Economy was the text used for a number of years in 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 course at 成人VR视频 in 鈥淓lements of Political Economy.鈥 Leacock was quite unreserved in his praise for Mill, whom he described as 鈥渙ne of the makers of the modern world ... as noble-minded as he was clear-headed,鈥13 and as someone 鈥渨ho grew younger as he got older鈥14 and a 鈥渉uman being first and an economist afterwards.鈥15 For Leacock, Mill鈥檚 real achievements were Principles of Political Economy and On Liberty and his having fortified and enlarged Adam Smith鈥檚 鈥渋ndustrial liberty by building into it the framework of individual freedom.鈥16
尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 policy views on production (where freedom should reign) and distribution (where state intervention is appropriate) take their inspiration directly from Mill, whose view is contained in the following passage from his Principles:
It is only in the backward countries of the world that increased production is still an important object: in those most advanced, what is economically needed is a better distribution . . . we may suppose this better distribution of property attained, by the joint effect of the prudence and frugality of individuals, and of a system of legislation favouring equality of fortunes, so far as is consistent with the just claim of the individual to the fruits, whether great or small, of his or her own industry.17
尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 indebtedness to Veblen, with whom he studied at The University of Chicago at the turn of the century, is neither acknowledged nor apparently even recognized. 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 handwritten chapter outline dated October 1, 1926 for a volume which was to have been entitled 鈥淐hapters in Political Economy: A View of the Rise and Development of Political Economy from Adam Smith Until Today Illustrated by Selections from Leading Economists鈥 contains the names of a number of twentieth century economists, including Frank Taussig, Gustav Cassel, Norman Angell, and John Maynard Keynes (subsequently crossed out), but not that of Veblen.18 Indeed Veblen is not even referred to in 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 writings until 1937 in My Discovery of the West,19 where Leacock traces the roots of Social Credit in part to Veblen鈥檚 writings.
Leacock speaks of Veblen鈥檚 main idea as being 鈥渢hat human industry is not carried on to satisfy human wants but in order to make money.鈥20 This does not quite capture the essence of Veblen鈥檚 distinction between making goods and making money. Moreover, this is not Veblen鈥檚 central point, but rather a derivative one. Key to Veblen鈥檚 approach is the constant interplay between technology and institutions, perhaps explaining in part why followers of Veblen are called 鈥渋nstitutionalists.鈥 To one familiar with Veblen, the influence on 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 thinking of Veblen鈥檚 鈥淲hy is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science鈥 (1898),21 The Cultural Incidence of the Machine Process鈥22 (1904), and The Vested Interests and the Common Man,23 inter alia, are unmistakable. Influence, of course, does not commence from the date of publication of a work, for as Leacock noted, Veblen gathered ideas from his turn-of-the-century lectures into later books.24
C. E. Ayres, one of the leading American exponents of Veblen鈥檚 thought, in his review of 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 The Unsolved Riddle, observed that 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 critique of economic science was 鈥渋n the spirit of the younger group of 鈥榠nstitutional鈥 economists (who are not mentioned, however); a trained psychic might even sense the presence of the spirit of Mr. Veblen.鈥25
Leacock on Public Policy:
In his approach to major economic questions, Leacock firmly opposed, and lavished harsh words on, both the laissez-faire implications of mainstream economics and socialist alternatives to the capitalist system. Leacock sought a middle course, rejecting both too much government interference26 and too little. While some of his formal analysis may be flawed, many of his recommendations still have merit, and his 1920 agenda for resolving the riddle of social justice is as timely now as when it was written.
Distribution. Before presenting his program of action in The Unsolved Riddle of Social Justice (1920), Leacock felt obliged to demonstrate the limitations of solutions dictated by supply and demand considerations:
Hitherto we have been hampered at every turn by the supposed obstacle of immutable economic laws. The theory of 鈥榥atural鈥 wages and prices of a supposed economic order that could not be disturbed, set up a sort of legislative paralysis. The first thing needed is to get away entirely from all such preconceptions, to recognize that the 鈥榥atural鈥 order of society, based on the 鈥榥atural鈥 liberty, does not correspond with real justice and real liberty at all, but works injustice at every turn. And at every turn intrusive social legislation must seek to prevent such injustice.27
John Stuart Mill had raised the desirability of income redistribution in 1848, Thorstein Veblen had caricatured the excesses of the leisure class in 1899, and World War I had demonstrated the scope for action. As Leacock observed:
In this respect five years of war have taught us more than a century of peace. It has set in a clear light new forms of social obligation. The war brought with it conscription鈥撯搉ot as we used to see it, as the last horror of military tyranny, but as the crowning pride of democracy. . . . But conscription has its other side. The obligation to die must carry with it the right to live. If every citizen owes it to society that he must fight for it in case of need, then society owes to every citizen the opportunity of a livelihood. 鈥楿nemployment鈥, in the case of the willing and able becomes henceforth a social crime. Every democratic government must hence: forth take as the starting point of its industrial policy, that there shall be no such thing as able bodied men and women 鈥榦ut of work鈥, looking for occupation and unable to find it. Work must either be found or must be provided by the state itself.28
For Leacock war finance had utilized a 鈥渢errific engine of taxation,鈥 which equally well could be utilized in peacetime for social betterment.29 There was no reason why 鈥渨ork and pay for the unemployed, maintenance for the infirm and aged, and education and opportunity for the children鈥 could not be provided.30 The children, however (尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 own son was five at the time), were the focal point for immediate action: 鈥淥ur feeble beginnings in the direction of housing, sanitation, child welfare and education, should be expanded at whatever cost into something truly national and all embracing.31 Leacock was emphatic that no child鈥檚 opportunity in life should be 鈥渙bliterated by the cruel fortune of the accident of birth.32
Those familiar with the enormous socio-economic problems of the less developed countries since World War II will recognize that 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 prescription for social justice overlaps considerably with the Basic Needs approach belatedly advocated by the World Bank in the late 1970s.33 For two decades development economists had focused their attention on the production side, leaving children to share their parents鈥 lot. To Leacock it was self-evident that a child鈥檚 brain and body are stunted by lack of food and air;34 today鈥檚 development economists required scholarly confirmation of this before reconsidering their policy approaches.
Production. The restoration of industrial production and employment levels after World War I involved lengthy delays. This was addressed by Leacock in his speech on the Gold Standard in 1924. Leacock saw the restoration of the Gold Standard as the key to restoring prosperity. Leacock argued against currency depreciation and applauded the British for not having abandoned a possible return to the pre-World War I sterling-dollar exchange rate. Leacock was, of course, by no means alone in recommending what proved to be a serious blunder, but he also offered extremely wise advice, which remains valid:
There is only one thing that you can do with gold, or at the best only two things鈥撯 spend it or lend it. . . . The true banking is to find somebody . . . with the industry and the perception and the intelligence to bring back your money ten times over. . ..Lend it to the right man. Don鈥檛 lend your money to a bunch of collateral that is dead; lend it to a man.
And the money in the United States should be loaned to the world, to each and every part that has potential wealth, to our Northwest, to the oil fields of Mesopotamia, wherever civilization can find new bases upon which to build up all we have lost in Europe. Lending the gold hoards of the United States is one of the most important financial steps to be taken.35
Using reserves or hoards to expand credit was thus seen by Leacock as a critical ingredient for economic expansion. Some of 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 proposals for restoring output levels during the Great Depression will be dealt with below.
International Trade and Tariffs. Tariffs, according to Leacock, had their place at a certain stage in the development of a nation, as did government interference with individual economic freedom. Leacock did not join mainstream economics in its elevation of free trade to the most desirable goal of public policy:
People agree to forget that this wonderful freedom of the working child was one part of a 鈥渟ystem of natural liberty,鈥 of which free trade was another. The two hung together. A convenient forgetfulness has pushed them apart.36
Innis appears to have been most offended by what he terms 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 鈥渋mperialism.鈥 Imperialism or, more precisely, co-operation with and integration within the British Empire was for Leacock what economists now call a 鈥渟econd best solution.鈥 Given the apparent impossibility of international economic unity, unity within the British Empire was much to be preferred to nationalist excesses, which were treated with scorn by Leacock: he speaks derisively, for example, of Canadian authorship being 鈥渆ncouraged like Canadian cheese and Canadian apples.鈥37 Even greater scorn was reserved for the excesses of federalism which bid fair already in the 1930s to split both Canada and Australia asunder and in 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 view were likely to stand in the way of recovery from the Depression. He spoke of Bennett鈥檚 program of social legislation, minimum wages, and maximum hours turning 鈥渙n whether the power of the Dominion extends to wages, etc. The Delphic provision of 鈥榩roperty and civil rights鈥 will block all economic progress.鈥38
Leacock viewed Empire unity as the only way that the members of the Empire, including Great Britain, could hope to offset American economic hegemony. The Americans were to be displaced by recourse to their own methods: use of the tariff; standardization of processes, methods, and machines; unification of weights, measures, and money (including, ideally decimal currency in Britain); and, in general, the combining of British and Dominion manufacture, capital, labour, technique, research, and industrial science39 Leacock recommended in particular an Empire super-tariff (he mentions fifteen per cent for purposes of illustration) which would apply to trade outside of the Empire and initially be added to all existing tariff levels.40 Leacock was essentially proposing for the Empire arrangements comparable in some ways to those which later formed the basis for the European Common Market.
Leacock on Economic Science:
Leacock is said to have remarked that if one could teach a parrot to say 鈥渟upply鈥 and 鈥渄emand鈥 one would have an economist. This would seem to be one of his milder pronouncements on the discipline. In Hellements of Hickonomics, Leacock observed of political economy: 鈥淗ere is an obstinate and crabbed science, living on facts and figures, untouched by imagination.鈥 鈥淓conomic scholasticism is drowsing into final oblivion鈥 behind locked doors. 鈥楾he time had come for political economy to 鈥渁lter or perish.鈥41 In the Preface to the Hellements, Leacock observed:
I think the whole science is a wreck and has got to be built up again. For our social problems there is about as much light to be found in the older economics as from a glowworm.42
The Hellements was published the same year as John Maynard Keynes鈥 The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money. Keynes was, indeed, trying to rebuild the science so that social problems might be resolved. Leacock might have found a careful reading of Keynes quite flattering: some of the central elements of analysis and policy in 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 1933 Plan to Relieve the Depression are at the heart of Keynes鈥 General Theory. Leacock had observed of the Depression:
It grows upon what it feeds on. Each time a worker is thrown out of employment, there is a loss of purchasing power; with each loss of purchasing power, another man is thrown out of work. There is no end, no stop.43
This might be considered a reasonable approximation to the process described later by Keynes. One might wish only to add a reference to expectations, as well as an explanation as to why employment and income might not continue to fall.44
For both Keynes and Leacock, although the elements of their explanations differ markedly, recovery from the Depression can be accomplished through increases in the money supply and public works expenditures. For Leacock a gap between profits and wages would serve as a stimulus to resumption of production and this could be accomplished by inflation produced 鈥渂y the circulation of great quantities of paper money, beyond all basis of physical value or redemption.鈥45 For Keynes, increases in the money supply worked on profits through expanding purchasing power rather than through price increases. Had the following passage, which Leacock would have appreciated, been penned by Leacock rather than Keynes, it would have been denounced as half-baked or absurd:
If the Treasury were to fill old bottles with banknotes, bury them at suitable depths in disused coalmines which are then filled up to the surface with town rubbish, and leave it to private enterprise on well-tried principles of laissez-faire to dig the notes up again (the right to do so being obtained, of course, by tendering for leases of the note-bearing territory), there need be no more unemployment and, with the help of the repercussions, the real income of the community, and its capital wealth also, would probably become a good deal greater than it actually is. It would, indeed, be more sensible to build houses and the like; but if there are political and practical difficulties in the way of this, the above would be better than nothing.46
Leacock reacted, not to Keynes鈥 ideas, but rather to his mathematical notation, in an unpublished, undated broadside entitled 鈥淭he Invasion of Human Thought by Mathematical Symbols: A Call to Arms.47 Leacock does not identify the economist said to be holding one of the most respected chairs in England lest he 鈥渟hould be crushed flat at once under the deadweight of prestige and authority,鈥 but he does reproduce exactly Keynes鈥 equation relating the proportional changes in total demand and investment.48 Leacock refers to mathematical economics as a 鈥渞acket鈥 and argues that it is:
no aid in calculating the incalculable. You cannot express the warmth of emotion in calories, the pressure on the market in horse-power, and the buoyancy of credit in specific gravity! Yet this is . . . what the pseudo-mathematicians try to do when they invade the social sciences. The conceptions dealt with in politics and economics and psychology, the ideas of valuation, preference, willingness and unwillingness, antipathy, desires etc., cannot be put into quantitative terms.49
He goes on to speculate as to the consequences if the 鈥渋nvasion鈥 were to spread to poetry, and renders 鈥淭he Charge of the Light Brigade鈥 as follows:50
(l/2 + l/2 + l/2)/600 = 600 - N
W. H. Dawson in his review of Economic Prosperity in the British Empire suggests that 鈥渢he sympathetic reader will not be likely to discard the good grain because something that looks suspiciously like chaff occasionally lies alongside of it.鈥51 In 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 many writings on economics there is an ever changing relationship between the serious and the apparently frivolous. There is, however, sufficient grain to repay the effort in insights and still timely counsel.
There is, of course, reward in that which 鈥渓ooks suspiciously like chaff鈥 as well. Take, for example, 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 musings on the question of the length of the working day:
If we could in imagination disregard for a moment all question of how the hours of work are to be shortened and how production is to be maintained and ask only what would be the ideal number of the daily hours of compulsory work, for character鈥檚 sake, few of us would put them at more than four or five. Many of us, as applied to ourselves, at least, would take a chance on character at two.52
Leacock wrote to influence public opinion on what he viewed to be major policy issues of his era. He chose to address neither an academic audience, whose formal analyses he held in disdain, nor the policy makers of the day, but rather the common man. He believed this to require 鈥渁 gay book on political economy for reading in a hammock.鈥53 Apparently Leacock believed that the very seriousness of the question required the counterweight of levity, if one hoped to make one鈥檚 point. And yet his point was not made: the very device with which Leacock hoped to gain attention appears to have contributed to his relative neglect. His light-hearted, increasingly superficial treatment of questions of national policy, combined with the public expectation of mere levity from his pen, assured that his works did not stir thought on the great questions of his time.
References:
- Harold Innis, 鈥淪tephen Butler Leacock 1869-1944,鈥 Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science (CJEPS), 10 (May 1944), 216-26. Innis鈥 lecture was one in a series marking the fiftieth anniversary of the Department of Political Economy of the University of Toronto in 1938. The lectures in the series devoted to William James Ashley and Adam Shortt were published in 1938 in the CJEPS and The Commerce Journal.
- Ibid., p. 226.
- Ibid. See also p. 219 (鈥淚n 1907 an ominous storm of imperialism broke over him and carried him from his moorings鈥), p. 221 (鈥渢hrown off his stride by imperialism鈥), and p. 225 (鈥渢he difficulties under which he laboured in the face of the demands of imperialism鈥).
- Ibid., p. 221. Craufurd D. W. Goodwin is far more severe than Innis in his judgement of Leacock the economist: 鈥淚t was unfortunate for both Leacock and for Canadian economics that he was forced to earn a living from a subject which he disliked, was unable to comprehend and took time away from areas where he made best use of his talents.鈥 Goodwin, Canadian Economic Thought: The Political Economy of a Developing Nation 1814-1914 (Durham. N.C.: Duke University Press, 1961), p. 193. See also pp. 190-93.
- Innis, p. 226.
- 鈥淲hat is Left of Adam Smith?鈥, CJEPS, I (February 1935). 41-51.
- Innis, p. 226.
- Alan Bowker. The Social Criticism of Stephen Leacock: The Unsolved Riddle of Social Justice and Other Essavs (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1973), pp. xix. See also p. xxxviii.
- 成人VR视频 Archives, Sir Arthur Currie Papers. file C63. Leacock to Currie, May 26, 1930.
- Ibid., Currie to F 1. Kerr [Ker], May 13, 1933.
- Innis, p. 225.
- W. A. Mackintosh. 鈥淎dam Shortt, 1859-1931,鈥 CJEPS, IV (May 1938), 164-76.
- Our Heritage of Liberty: Its Origin, Its Achievement, Its Crisis: A Book for War Time聽(London: John Lane, The Bodley Head, 1942), p. 48.
- 鈥淭he Economic Analysis of Industrial Depression,鈥 Papers and Proceedings of the Canadian Political Science Association, V (1933), p. 8.
- Economic Prosperity in the British Empire (Toronto: Macmillan, 1930), p. 165.
- Our Heritage, p. 48.
- John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy, 5th ed. (New York: D. Appleton, 1865), vol. II, p. 338.
- 成人VR视频 Library, Rare Books Department, Stephen Leacock Collection, Mss, Box 12. There are only twenty-seven pages of this manuscript; page 28 indicates that material from an Ottawa lecture was to follow at that point. The text covers the chapter outline, preface and Chapter I dealing with Adam Smith and the Wealth of Nations.
- My Discovery of the West (Toronto: Thomas Allen, 1937), pp. 136-38.
- Ibid., p. 137. See also Carl Berger, 鈥淭he Other Mr. Leacock,鈥 Canadian Literature, 55 (Winter 1973), 32-33.
- The Quarterly Journal of Economics, XII (July 1898).
- 鈥淭he Cultural Incidence . . .鈥 appeared as Chapter IX of Veblen鈥檚 The Theory of Business Enterprise (1904).
- The Vested Interests and the Common Man: (鈥淭he Modern Point of View and the New Order鈥) (New York: B. W. Huebsch, 1919).
- My Discovery, p. 137.
- C. E. Ayres, review of The Unsolved Riddle of Social Justice by Stephen Leacock, Journal of Political Economy, 28 (May 1920), 439-40. For Claude T Bissell, the influence on 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 humour of Thorstein Veblen (and Mark Twain) is unmistakable: 鈥Arcadian Adventures with the Idle Rich was almost a fictional companion piece to The Theory of the Leisure Class.鈥 鈥淗aliburton, Leacock and the American Humorous Tradition,鈥 Canadian Literature, 39 (Winter 1969), 14.
- The Unsolved Riddle of Social Justice (London: John Lane, The Bodley Head, 1920) and 鈥淭he Proper Limitations of State Interference,鈥 an address before the Empire Club of Canada, Toronto (March 6, 1924), 14 pp.
- The Unsolved Riddle, p. 133. 28
- Ibid., pp. 119-20.
- Ibid., pp. 131-32.
- Ibid., p. 130.
- Ibid., p. 129.
- Ibid.
- Paul Streeten, et al., First Things First: Meeting Basic Human Needs in Developing Countries聽(New York: Oxford University Press, 1981).
- Ibid., p. 219.
- 鈥淭he Gold Standard,鈥 an address before the 1924 Life Insurance Educational Congress, Toronto, p. 8.
- Economic Prosperity, p. 166.
- Ibid., p. 231. For a discussion of the movement in Canada for imperial unity and 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 relation to it see Carl Berger, The Sense of Power: Studies in the Ideas of Canadian Imperialism 1867-1914 (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1970).
- 鈥淓conomic Separatism in the British Empire,鈥 The Quarterly Review, no. 525 (July 1935), p. 9.
- Economic Prosperity, pp. 177-79.
- 40. Ibid., pp. 163-64.
- Hellements of Hickonomics in Hiccoughs of Verse Done in Our Social Planning Mill (New York: Dodd, Mead, 1936), p. 84.
- Ibid., p. vi.
- Stephen 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 Plan to Relieve the Depression in 6 Days, To Remove It in 6 Months, To Eradicate It in 6 Years (Toronto: Macmillan, 1933), p. 1.
- J. M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money (New York: Harcourt, Brace, 1936), p. 98.
- Stephen 尝别补肠辞肠办鈥檚 Plan, p. 6.
- Keynes, p. 129.
- 成人VR视频 Library, Leacock Mss, Box 4.
- Keynes, p. 126, n. 2. Keynes did not hold a chair, but rather was a Fellow and Bursar of King鈥檚 College, Cambridge.
- 鈥淭he Invasion of Human Thought.鈥
- Ibid.
- W. H. Dawson, review of Economic Prosperity in the British Empire, by Stephen Leacock,聽The Economic Journal (June 1931), pp. 295-97.
- The Unsolved Riddle, pp. 137-38.
- Ibid., p. 99.
Special thanks go to Kim Reany for deciphering and typing successive drafts and to Rosalind Boyd-Jeeroburkhan, Chris Green, James R. Mallory, Carman Miller, Tom Naylor, Ian Ross Robertson and William G. Watson for helpful comments and suggestions.